The end of free-lunch economics and its worrisome implications

Bills for indiscriminate fiscal and monetary support eventually have to be paid mostly by people who are least able to afford it

Raghuram G. Rajan
Published2 Feb 2022, 10:44 PM IST
Photo: AP
Photo: AP

Smart economic policymaking invariably requires trading off some pain today for greater future gains. But this is a difficult proposition politically, especially in democracies. It is easier for elected leaders to indulge their constituents immediately, on the hope that the bill will not arrive while they are still in office. Moreover, those who bear the pain caused by a policy are not necessarily those who will gain from it.

That is why today’s advanced economies created mechanisms that allow them to make hard choices when necessary. Chief among these are independent central banks and mandated limits on budget deficits. Importantly, political parties reached a consensus to establish and back these mechanisms irrespective of their own political priorities. One reason many emerging markets have swung from crisis to crisis is that they failed to achieve such a consensus. But recent history shows that they, too, are becoming less tolerant of pain, perhaps because their own political consensus has eroded.

Financial markets have become volatile once again, owing to fears that the US Federal Reserve will have to tighten its monetary policy significantly to control inflation. But many investors still hope that the Fed will go easy if asset prices start to fall substantially. If the Fed proves them right, it will become that much harder to normalize financial conditions in the future.

Investors’ hope that the Fed will prolong the party is not baseless. In late 1996, Fed Chair Alan Greenspan warned of financial markets’ “irrational exuberance.” But markets shrugged off the warning and were proven correct. Perhaps chastened by the harsh political reaction to Greenspan’s speech, the Fed did nothing. And when stock markets eventually crashed in 2000, the Fed cut rates, ensuring that the recession was mild. In a testimony to the congressional Joint Economic Committee the previous year, Greenspan argued that while the Fed could not prevent “the inevitable economic hangover” from an asset-price boom, it could “mitigate the fallout when it occurs and, hopefully, ease the transition to the next expansion.” The Fed thus assured traders and bankers that if they collectively gambled on similar assets, it would not limit the upside, but it would limit the downside if their bets turned bad. Subsequent Fed interventions have entrenched such beliefs, making it even harder for the Fed to rein in financial markets with modest moves. And now that much more tightening and consequent pain may be needed, a consensus in favour of it might be harder to achieve.

Fiscal policy is also guilty of peddling supposedly painless economic measures. Most would agree that the pandemic created a need for targeted spending (through generous unemployment benefits, for example) to shield the hardest-hit households. But, in the event, the spending was anything but targeted. The US Congress passed multi-trillion-dollar bills offering something for everyone. The Paycheck Protection Program (PPP), for example, provided $800 billion in grants (effectively) for small businesses across the board. A new study from MIT’s David Autor and his colleagues estimates that the programme helped preserve 2-3 million job-years of employment over 14 months, at a stupendous cost of $170,000-$257,000 per job-year. Worse, only 23-34% of this money went directly to workers who would otherwise have lost their jobs. The balance went to creditors, business owners and shareholders. All told, an estimated three-quarters of PPP benefits went to the top one-fifth of earners.

Of course, the programme may have saved some firms that otherwise would have collapsed. But at what cost? While capitalists anticipate profits, they also sign up for possible failure. Moreover, many small businesses are tiny operations without much organizational capital. If a small bakery had to close, the economic fallout would have been mitigated by the enhanced unemployment insurance. And if it had a loyal clientele, it could restart after the pandemic, perhaps with a little help from a bank.

The standard line is that this unconstrained spending was driven by a sense that unprecedented times called for unprecedented measures. In fact, it was the response to the 2008 global financial crisis that broke the previous consensus for more prudent policies. Lasting public resentment that Wall Street had been helped more than Main Street motivated politicians in both major US parties to spend with abandon when the pandemic hit.

But targeted unemployment benefits were associated with America’s Democrats. Republicans sought wins for their own constituencies. And who better to support than small American businesses?

While political fractures drove up spending, budget hawks were nowhere to be found: Their voices had been steadily drowned out by economists. In addition to the cranks who show up periodically to advocate ostensibly free lunches through money- financed spending, a growing chorus of mainstream economists had been arguing that prevailing low interest rates gave developed countries significantly more room to expand fiscal deficits. Politicians who were eager to justify their policies ignored these economists’ caveats: that spending had to be sensible and interest rates had to stay low. Only the headline message mattered, and anyone who suggested otherwise was dismissed as a hair-shirt fanatic.

Historically, it has been the Fed’s job to take away the monetary punch bowl before the party gets frenzied and Congress’s job to be prudent on fiscal deficits and debt. But the Fed’s desire to spare the market pain has driven more risk-taking and reinforced expectations of further interventions. The Fed’s actions have also added to pressure on the US Congress to do its bit for Main Street, which in turn has led to inflation and a belief that the Fed will back off from raising rates.

All this makes a return to the previous consensus more difficult. When the Fed does raise rates significantly, the government’s costs of servicing its debt from past spending will limit future spending, including on policies to reduce inequality, combat future emergencies and tackle climate change.

Every economy has a limited reservoir of policy credibility and resources, which are best used to mitigate genuine distress, not to shield those who can bear some pain. If everyone wants a free lunch, the bill eventually will be paid by those least able to afford it. Emerging-market economies have had to learn this the hard way. Developed countries may have to learn it again. ©2022/Project Syndicate

Raghuram G. Rajan is former governor of the Reserve Bank of India, professor of finance at the University of Chicago Booth School of Business, and the author, most recently, of ‘The Third Pillar: How Markets and the State Leave the Community Behind’

Catch all the Business News, Market News, Breaking News Events and Latest News Updates on Live Mint. Download The Mint News App to get Daily Market Updates.

Business NewsOpinionViewsThe end of free-lunch economics and its worrisome implications
MoreLess